Capitalism's Best Mix

To Our Readers

The Moscow Times welcomes letters to the editor. Letters for publication should be signed and bear the signatory's address and telephone number.
Letters to the editor should be sent by fax to (7-495) 232-6529, by e-mail to oped@imedia.ru, or by post. The Moscow Times reserves the right to edit letters.

Email the Opinion Page Editor



Many people assumed that when the Berlin Wall fell in 1989, capitalism had won the ideological Cold War and communism had lost. But, while capitalism -- defined as an economic system built on private ownership of property -- clearly has prevailed, there are many differences among the nearly 200 countries that now practice it in some form.

It is useful to divide the capitalist economies into four broad categories. While many economies straddle several of these, most economies fall primarily into one of them. The following typology helps explain why some economies grow more rapidly than others.

• Oligarchic capitalism. This is where power and money are highly concentrated among the elite. It is the worst form of capitalism, not only because of the extreme inequality in income and wealth that such economies tolerate, but also because the elite do not promote growth as the central goal of economic policy. Instead, oligarchs fix the rules to maximize their own income and wealth. Such arrangements prevail in large parts of Latin America, the Middle East and Africa.

• State-guided capitalism. Here, governments attempt to achieve economic growth by favoring specific firms or industries. Governments allocate credit through direct bank ownership or by guiding credit decisions by privately owned banks. They also provide direct subsidies or tax incentives, grant trade protection or use other regulatory devices in an attempt to pick their favorite winners.

Southeast Asian economies have demonstrated great success with state guidance, and, until the late 1990s, there were calls in the United States to emulate their practices. But the Achilles' heel of state guidance is that once such economies near the "production-possibility frontier," policymakers run out of industries and technologies to copy. When government officials rather than markets try to choose the next winners, they run a great risk of choosing the wrong industries, or channeling too much investment into existing sectors. Such a tendency contributed significantly to the Asian financial crisis from 1997 to 1998.

• Big firm or managerial capitalism. This is characterized by large firms -- often called "national champions" -- that dominate production and employment. Smaller enterprises exist, but they are typically retail or service establishments with one or only a few employees. Firms get to be large by exploiting economies of scale, refining and mass-producing the radical innovations developed by entrepreneurs. Western European economies and Japan are leading exemplars of managerial capitalism, which, like state guidance, also has delivered strong economic performance.

But managerial capitalism, too, has its Achilles' heel. Bureaucratic enterprises are typically allergic to taking big risks -- that is, developing and commercializing the radical innovations that expand the production-possibility frontier and generate large sustained jumps in productivity and thus in economic growth.

Large firms are relatively risk-averse, not only because they are bureaucracies, with layers of management required to sign off on any innovation, but also because they are reluctant to back innovations that threaten to render obsolete the products or services that currently account for their profits. In our view, the limits of managerial capitalism explain why, after approaching U.S. levels of per capita income in the late 1980s, both Western Europe and Japan failed to match the United States' productivity resurgence, driven by the information-technology boom, that began in the 1990s.

• Entrepreneurial capitalism. Here, dynamism comes from new firms that historically have commercialized the radical innovations, which keeps expanding the production-possibility frontier. Examples from the last two centuries include such transformative products and innovations as railroads, automobiles and airplanes; telegraph, telephones, radio and television; and the various technologies responsible for the IT revolution, including both mainframe and personal computers, routers and other hardware devices, and much of the software that operates them.

To be sure, no economy can realize its full potential only by having entrepreneurial firms. The optimal mix of firms contains a healthy dose of large enterprises, which have the financial and human resources to refine and mass-produce radical innovations, along with newer firms.

It required Boeing and other large aircraft manufacturers, for example, to commercialize what the Wright brothers pioneered, or Ford and General Motors to mass-produce the automobile, and so on. But without entrepreneurs, few of the really bold innovations that have shaped our modern economy and our lives would be in place.

The challenge, then, for all economies seeking to maximize their growth potential is to find the right mix of managerial and entrepreneurial capitalism. Economies where entrepreneurs now flourish must not become complacent. State-guided economies can continue their rapid growth path, but ultimately they will need to make a transition to a suitable blend of the other two forms of "good capitalism" if they want to continue rapid growth.

India, China and Russia are already moving in this direction to one degree or another. The hardest challenge will be for economies mired in oligarchic capitalism to accomplish a similar transition. It may take nothing less than revolution -- ideally peaceful -- to replace the elites who now dominate these economies and societies, and for whom growth is not the central objective.



William Baumol is professor of economics and director of the Berkeley Entrepreneurship Center at New York University. Robert E. Litan is senior fellow in the Economic Studies and Global Economics Programs at the Brookings Institution. Carl Schramm is a Batten fellow at the Darden School of Business at the University of Virginia. © Project Syndicate.